FAQ Number 11

How Real Options See the Choice of Mutually Exclusive Alternatives to Develop a Project?

Answer: Real options theory provides new insights on this very interesting and important application.

A large Petrobras-PUC research on this topic is finishing in 2004.
The aim of this research was the comparison of alternatives of oilfield development, alternatives of investment in information, alternatives with option to expand, etc., before commit a large investment in an offshore oilfield development. The project topic covered in this FAQ finished in 2003, with a C++ software and a paper by Dias & Rocha & Teixeira (2003), submitted to publication.

Let us analyze the case of mutually exclusive alternatives to develop an oilfield. One simple model is presented by Dixit: "Choosing Among Alternative Discrete Investment Projects Under Uncertainty". Economic Letters, vol.41, 1993, pp.265-288.

This model is summarized below, with a little adaptation using the concept of economic quality of a developed reserve(q).
If the oil price values P and one barrel of reserve values V, the quality q = V/P. Here the normalized (by B) net present value NPV/B = q P - D, where B is the reserve volume (number of barrels) and D is the normalized (by B) development cost (in present value).
OBS: In more recent papers I call V = q P B, but in this FAQ the notation is V = q P because we are working with normalized values ($/bbl) instead $.

The alternatives have different investment costs. Higher investment alternatives have benefit of faster production (more wells and/or higher processing facilities capacity) and/or lower operational costs. What is the optimal capital intensity under uncertainty?

First, let us see the best decision at the expiration. The picture below illustrates this case:

Higher quality q means higher inclination in the chart above.

Before the expiration the analysis is a bit more complex. One alternative alone can be "deep-in-the-money", but the existence of other alternatives can change this, and the manager can wait and eventually to invest in a larger scale alternative.
The picture below shows this case.

The alternative 1 could justify an earlier investment if the inclination (the reserve quality) become a bit more inclined.
Other important point is: with passage of time, the options curve move down and for a region of prices, the option curve of alternative 2 can be below the option curve of the alternative 1, so that is possible to choose an earlier exercise of alternative 1 for prices at or above the P1* and lower than the intersection of the payoffs from alternatives 1 and 2.

It is easy to get the curves for the option alternatives with spreadsheets like Timing. To compare, superpose the option curves and look for the higher one. With this practical approach we can see some special cases not addressed before by Dixit (1993). Even being an approximation (see below why), the numerical error on the value of the option is very small so that it possible to see that in most cases there is an intermediate waiting region between the exercise of alternatives 2 and 3. So that for P > P*2, we can see a region that the option value of waiting (F3) is higher than both NPV2 and NPV3.
Motived with this somelike surprising experimental early result, in 2000 were started two projects between PUC and Petrobras - from the Pravap-14 research projects portfolio, which confirmed this hypothesis. One Pravap-14 project was a more flexible and general determination of the optimal rules regions by using genetic algorithms (developed with Electrical Engineering Department). The other Pravap-14 project was more rigorous (but specific for simpler cases) using the traditional differential equation approach (developed with Industrial Engineering Department). Both used finite-lived options. In year 2002 we started the second phase of both projects, adding other realistic details with more complex issues.
By using a C++ PRAVAP-14 software developed at Industrial Engineering Department (PUC-Rio), it is possible to get the following thresholds chart showed below (and presented at MIT Seminar on Real Options, May 2002).

Investment and waiting thresholds along the time chart

Working independently and with perpetual options, Décamps & Mariotti & Villeneuve (2003) proved mathematically that the waiting region around the point of indifference between NPV2 and NPV3 always occurs (non-empty region) if sometimes is optimal to invest in alternative 2. They showed that if "investment in the smaller scale project is sometimes optimal, ... the optimal investment region is dichotomous.". In their proposition 3.2, they show that the indifference point where NPV2 = NPV3 does not belong to the exercise region. They proved with help of the sophisticated concept of local time for the continuous semimartingale P applied at this indifference point. Before this paper, I was thinking that the Dixit's (1993) claim even not being typical could be possible. But they proved that it cannot be possible.

Probably the conclusion from Décamps & Mariotti & Villeneuve (2003) is even more general, being also true for finite-lived options except at the expiration.
I thank to Professor Thomas Mariotti for letting me know about this paper and for the nice discussion.
With this new insight in mind, we can correct the Dixit's option value chart by setting a case that always occurs in the figure below (analogous to Figure 1 from Décamps & Mariotti & Villeneuve, 2003):

Option chart showing the intermediate waiting region

In the above figure, the option curve (red line) in the superior part of this figure (between PW23 and P*3) is the intermediate waiting region. Décamps & Mariotti & Villeneuve (2003) showed that this region always exists (if sometimes is optimal exercise alternative 2, as occurs in the figure).
Numerically the error can be small if exercising the option (higher NPV as suggested by Dixit in 1993) rather than waiting in this intermediate optimal waiting region. So, even not being correct, the error using the Dixit's insight can be small in practice. However, the size of the waiting interval (between PW23 and P*3) can be a large range.

The full results from the Pravap-14 project (including cases with mean reversion) is reported in a paper by Dias & Rocha & Teixeira (2003), submitted to publication.



Go to the Next FAQ: 12) Will the total volatility of the model be increased if I add others sources of uncertainty?


Back to the FAQ's List

Back to Contents